Previous Page  7 / 50 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 7 / 50 Next Page
Page Background

7

Currently, the favourite explanation of self-control

problems given by open-minded economists is the

occurrence of present bias (Delaney and Lades, 2015;

O’Donoghue and Rabin, 2015), which suggests that the

conventional assumption of time-consistent decisions

and exponential discounting of future values is wrong.

When considering trade-offs on two future moments,

present biased preferences denote stronger weight to

the earlier moment as it gets closer (see O’Donoghue

and Rabin, 1999, 2001), describing, in this sense, a

conflict between an individual’s short-run and long run

“selves”.

This was initially formalized in the classic quasi-

hyperbolic discounting model of Laibson (1997):

where β and δ represent discount factors (usually with

β,δ<1), being the former a measure of present bias

and the later a measure of impatience. In other words,

outcomes delayed by an additional time period have

their values multiplied by δ, obtaining then its time-

discounted value, and all non-immediate outcomes are

multiplied by β, generating a short-term desire – the

so-called present bias – and potentially a self-control

failure. Those familiarised with behavioural economics

would promptly recognize that this model follows the

ideas of dual process theories, which assume that

human decision making consists of two distinct systems,

well-described by Daniel Kahneman (2003) in his Nobel

Prize lecture.

Despite its rich descriptive power, the quasi-hyperbolic

discounting model does not fully explain why time-

inconsistent decisions and self-control failures arise,

requiring then further extensions. In order to better

describe the nature of present bias, Delaney and Lades

(2015) built on psychological insights that understand

self-control problems as intrapersonal conflicts between

temptations and the ability of self-control. Basically,

a failure occur when the temptation dominates an

individual’s capacity to resist (self-control). Formally,

they proposed the following microfoundation for the

present bias parameter:

ntrol failure. Those familiarised with behavioural economics would promptly

cognize that this model follows the ideas of dual process theories, which assume that

man decision making consists of two distinct systems, well-described by Daniel

ahneman (2003) in his Nobel Prize lecture.

espite its rich descriptive power, t e quasi-hyperbolic discounting model does not

lly explain why time-inconsistent decisions and self-con rol failures arise, requiring

en further ex nsions. I order o better describ the ature of present bias, Delaney

d Lades (2015) built on psychological insights that underst nd self-control problems

intrapersonal conflicts between temptations and the ability f se f-control. Basically,

failure occur when the temptation d m ates an individual’s capacity to resist (self

-

ntrol). Formally, they pro osed the following microfoundation for the present bias

rameter:

=

1 1+ (1− )

(2)

here

T

> 0 represents temptations’ level and 0 <

SC

<1 represents self-control ability.

his formalisation suggests that present bias is positively related to temptations and

gatively related to self-control, so an individual needs self-control only when tempted.

his development allows the differentiation between heterogeneous decision makers in

rms of their sophistication (

O’

Donoghue and Rabin, 1999). For instance, sophisticated

dividuals are conscious that temptations and self-control weaknesses are likely events

everyday life, and so is present bias, so they might engage in proactive commitments

avoid or mitigate the effect of future temptations. On the opposite level, completely

where T > 0 represent temptations’ level and 0 < SC

<1 represents self-control ability. This formalisa n

suggests that present bias is positively related to

temptations and negatively related to self-control, so an

individual needs self-control only when tempted.

This development allows the differentiation between

heterogeneous decision makers in terms of their

sophistication (O’Donoghue and Rabin, 1999). For

instance, sophisticated individuals are conscious

that temptations and self-control weaknesses are

likely events in everyday life, and so is present bias,

so they might engage in proactive commitments to

avoid or mitigate the effect of future temptations. On

the opposite level, completely naïve individuals are

unaware of their present bias and believe they will not

encounter any temptations in the future. This is in line

with empirical studies on personality and individual

differences showing that individuals high in trait

self-control are more likely to avoid temptation and

distraction, rather than simply resisting goal-inhibiting

impulses (Ent et al., 2015).

The concepts of present bias and sophistication within

the context of self-control have become decisive for

policymaking and regulation. For example, present

biased sophisticated savers may demand financial

products which prescribe penalties and liquidity

constraints, such as mutual funds and pension plans,

to help them to overcome self-control problems. Also,

these individuals may avoid credit card use in order to

mitigate the occurrence of consumption temptations

and abuse of credit use. Sophisticated investors may

follow investment strategies that are tied to specific

asset allocation rules or non-discretionary trading

systems to avoid overconfidence and the desire of

maintaining losing trades for longer periods than the

profitable ones – the so-called disposition effect. At

the same time, a benevolent financial regulator would

wish to protect naïve participants that lack financial

literacy or are simply unaware of the constant visceral

influences on financial decisions. The remainder of

this article covers some applications of the current

knowledge about self-control problems, their effects on

fina cial decision making and the suggestions of recent

emp ical studies.

1. Retir ent savings, self-awareness and commitment

mechanisms

Present bias leads people to save insufficiently for

r tirement: even when they wish to save more, they

fail to do so by procrastinating the decision to opt-

in a pension plan. It has also been suggested that

self-awareness regarding one’s biases might be a

stronger determinant of financial behaviour than their

direct effect itself. Theoretical predictions between

behavioural parameters and the role of sophistication

on retirement savings were exposed by Goda et al

(2015, p. 9). For instance, a sophisticated saver, aware of

1

Self-control is an important capacity that prevents people from acting on impulses

which has been identified as a critical human skill in both economics and psychology.

Economists often defined self-control as the ability to stick to prior plans and thus have

consistent intertemporal choices. In psychology, self-control is defined as the ability to

regulate one's behaviours, emotions, and thoughts. This article addresses recent

developments that are overcoming disciplinary boundaries in order to generate a more

coherent desc iption for the role f self-control o everyday inancial behaviour,

including the behaviour of the Chief Financial Officers. As they have to most important

financial role in the firms. We focus on applications closely related to policymaking and

financial regulation, such as: saving for retirement, indebtedness and investment

attitudes. The present discussion suggests that the trait of self-control might prevent

failures by avoiding rather than resisting t temptations.

First of all, t reader must be familiar with some key concepts often discu sed in the

self-control literature. Currently, the favourite explanation of self-control problems

given by open-minded economists is the occurrence of present bias (Delaney and Lades,

2015

; O’Donoghue and Rabin, 2015), which suggests that the conventional assumption

of time-consistent decisions and exponential discou ting of future values is wrong.

When considering trade-offs on two future moments, prese t biased prefere ces denote

stronger weight to the earlier moment as it gets closer (see

O’Donoghue and Rabin,

1999, 2001), describing, in this sense, a conflict between

an individual’s

short-run and

long run “selves”

.

This was initially formalized in the classic quasi-hyperbolic discounting model of

Laibson (1997):

( , … ,

) = ( ) + ∑ (

+

)

=1

(1)

where and represent discount factors (usually with ,

< 1

), being the former a

measure of present bias and the later a measure of impatience. In other words, outcomes

delayed by an additio al tim eriod have their values multiplied b , obtaining then

its time-discounted value, and all non-im ediate outcomes are multiplied by ,

generating a short-term desire

the so-called present bias

and potentially a self-